Sunday, 27 November 2011

Wal-Mart and Social Capital Stephan J. Goetz and Anil Rupasingha


Amer. J. Agric. Econ. 88, 5 (2006):1304-1310, in press.                                                            Page 1
Copyright 2006 American Agricultural Economics Association
Wal-Mart and Social Capital
Stephan J. Goetz and Anil Rupasingha
1
Economists increasingly recognize that markets exist within social and cultural contexts,
and that these contexts affect how resources are allocated to competing ends.  The social
economics literature views individuals as both affected by and affecting the environment in
which they live (e.g., Barrett 2005; Durlauf and Young 2001).  Contributors to this literature recognize that utility and happiness are relative concepts that depend on levels
achieved by peers (Layard 2005), and acknowledge that both utility and happiness can increase with levels of social interaction (Kahneman and Krueger 2006).  Further,  “because
social organization is typically characterized by multiple equilibria, small changes in economic conditions can lead to dramatic changes in the behavior of and membership in [social] groups and networks” (Barrett 2005, p.10).
 A far-reaching economic change is the recent rise of big-box retailing, led by Wal-Mart
Corp. (Fishman 2006).  While the chain’s adverse impact on mom-and-pop type retail outlets has been well-documented (Stone 1997, Irwin and Clark 2006), the second-round effects of such store closings on local social capital or civic capacity have not been studied.
For example, economic developers lament the fact that community civic capacity declines
when locally-owned banks go out of business or are taken over by national corporations.
Yet systematic evaluation of this phenomenon has remained elusive, because of the difficulty of measuring local social capital.
 Advances in the consistent measurement of county-level social capital (Rupasingha,
Goetz and Freshwater 2006) now make it possible to examine rigorously the impact of bigbox chains on the civic capacity of all rural and urban US counties.  Previous studies have
implemented the concept using trust, social norms or networks, following Putnam’s (2000)
seminal work, Bowling Alone.  These studies use cross-country comparisons based on individual-level data (the World Value Surveys, Knack and Keefer 1997), state-level data in the
U.S., (the General Social Survey, Glaeser, Laibson and Sacerdote 2002) or data collected in
individual-level surveys in specific contexts (Narayan and Prichett 1999).  
 In this article, we identify for the first time the independent effect of Wal-Mart stores
on social capital at the U.S. county-level during the 1990s.  We propose a conceptual model
of the processes leading to changes in social capital and hypothesize that big-box corporations, in which innovative business processes and management functions are handled out of
centralized headquarters, or outsourced to Asia, depress social capital stocks in local communities.  This compounds the adverse effects of losing local philanthropic capacity, reinvestment of surpluses (rents) and community-specific knowledge or capital.
 Questions surrounding social capital are hardly trivial for economists.  That social capital stocks matter for economic growth and poverty reduction is documented in an expanding literature (Knack and Keefer 1997, Rupasingha, Goetz and Freshwater 2002, Rupasin-

                                             
1
 Stephan J. Goetz is Professor of Agricultural and Regional Economics and Director of The Northeastern Regional Center for Rural Development, The Pennsylvania State University.  Anil Rupasingha is Assistant Professor of Economics at the American University of Sharjah in the United Arab
Emirates.  Support from the USDA/CSREES National Research Initiative, grant no. 2003-35401-
12936, as well as the authors’ host institutions is gratefully acknowledged, with the usual disclaimer. Amer. J. Agric. Econ. 88, 5 (2006):1304-1310, in press.                                                            Page 2
Copyright 2006 American Agricultural Economics Association
gha and Goetz 2003, and Goetz and Swaminathan 2006; see also, however, Schmid 2003),
although definitional and measurement issues remain.  Skinner and Staiger (2005) argue
that social capital stocks may explain state-level differences in the adoption of tractors and
hybrid corn.  This explanation contradicts Griliches’ (1957) argument that profitability and
incentives alone matter in technology adoption.
 We find that social capital stocks as measured by the density of social capitalgenerating establishments and various measures of civic participation (defined below) were
lower both in communities in which new Wal-Mart stores were built and in communities
that already had a Wal-Mart store at the beginning of the 1990s decade.  This finding adds
an important new dimension to the analysis of community-wide impacts of the chain, and
one more externality that needs to be considered when weighing its benefits.  
Conceptual Framework
The most visible and direct impact of Wal-Mart is usually the disappearance of small, locally-owned mom-and-pop type stores (Stone 1997).  In fact, Wal-Mart’s current PR campaign focuses on helping small local businesses -- even those with which it ostensibly competes.  Although new retail activity may emerge in the vicinity of a Wal-Mart, benefiting
from the additional traffic generated, the balance of evidence suggests a net loss in the
types of home-grown stores that have long existed in the community.  Embedded in these
stores and their owners are important social relationships, norms and trust that were built up
over time.  Sociologists refer to these storeowners as part of the local leadership class
(Tolbert, Lyson and Irwin 1998).  Recognizing the possibility of negative social capital, we
propose that on net these leaders not only have the best public interest of the community in
mind, but that they also understand the interpersonal dynamics of its members and their
various networks.  Thus, they can head off conflict and know how to get individuals to cooperate when a local problem requires group action.
 Virtually all research on Wal-Mart to date focuses on existing mom-and-pop retailers,
ignoring the elaborate but less visible supporting industry within communities that serves
these retailers.  This industry includes firms in the legal, accounting, transportation, warehousing, logistics, financial, publishing and advertising sectors that work closely with the
retailers.  In particular, local lawyers, accountants and bankers provide essential support
services for the mom-and-pop stores, and these individuals typically are community leaders.  With the arrival of Wal-Mart, and the attendant reduction in the demand for their services, they leave the community to pursue opportunities elsewhere.  In the process, the social capital they embody is destroyed, and their entrepreneurial skills and other forms of
location-specific human capital are forever lost to the community.
 Local stores may commission the design and creation of flyers for insertion into local
newspapers and they may take out ads.  Wal-Mart does not follow this practice.  With local
advertising revenues drying up, compounding the effect of the Internet, local newspapers
become unprofitable, eliminating a source of livelihood for local opinion leaders.  Wholesaling jobs, often higher-paying than retail jobs, disappear as local stores no longer require
services of local wholesalers, and local transport, logistics and storage firms.  Thus, a reverse multiplier works its way through the community.  
 Social interaction among local entrepreneurs represents an important venue for sustaining and enhancing embedded social capital.  As shoppers drive to the outskirts where Wal-Amer. J. Agric. Econ. 88, 5 (2006):1304-1310, in press.                                                            Page 3
Copyright 2006 American Agricultural Economics Association
Mart is located to buy goods and services, downtown stores close and local coffee shops
see their customer base dry up.  Opportunities for dialogue and interaction among local
citizens may be reduced.  Likewise, local entrepreneurs may have fewer opportunities to
sell innovative new products. Wal-Mart in fact has created a lottery for entrepreneurs.
Those who succeed and get their products onto the stores’ shelves hit the jackpot, at least in
the short-term, until the chain imposes its annual price cutting discipline (Fishman 2006).
Others are cut out of the market as they are unable to garner shelf space because local
stores have disappeared.
 Wal-Mart does not employ the services of these local firms that form the backbone of
local social capital.  Instead, the chain’s enormous efficiency lies in its ability to concentrate back office and supporting functions in one place, Bentonville, AR, as well as in offshoring them to China or India.  Given the global reach of Wal-Mart’s supply chain, not
doing so would be irrational.
Model and Data
Our primary dependent variable is the county-level measure of social capital developed in
Rupasingha, Goetz and Freshwater (2006).  This variable is the first principal component of
five variables, including the number of social capital-generating associations per 10,000
residents (civic organizations, bowling alleys, golf courses, fitness centers, sports organizations, religious organizations, political organizations, labor organizations, business organizations and professional organizations); voter turnout in the 2000 presidential election;
number of tax exempt non-profit organizations per 10,000; and participation in the decennial Census in 2000.  The latter variable captures a sense of belonging to the nation,
whereas the former represents both local and national allegiance, depending on how important local as opposed to national issues are in bringing voters to the polls.  Following
Tolbert, Lyson and Irwin (1998), we also use church adherence to measure local civic engagement.  We present regression results for each of the separate components as well. Table 1 provides definitions and summary statistics.
 Our statistical equations are based on a model of household utility maximization that
includes income as a measure of the opportunity cost of time facing decisionmakers.  This
model is derived in detail in Rupasingha, Goetz and Freshwater (2006).  The model predicts a different response to the civic task of filling out a Census form (which can be done
in the convenience of the home and then mailed in, and which occurs only once every decade) and visiting a polling station every two years, for example.  
 Regressors include, with expected signs in parentheses, educational attainment (+),
ethnic diversity (−), inequality (−), female labor force participation (+), rural (+)/urban (−)
stratification, home ownership (+), age (+,−) with a quadratic effect, family households (+)
and households with children (+), migration behavior (+ for lack of migration, i.e., “stayer”
percentages), and employment in manufacturing (+), agriculture (+) and professionals (+).
These variables are measured in 1990, with a ten-year lag relative to the year in which our
dependent variables are measured to reduce endogeneity bias.  Rupasingha, Goetz and
Freshwater (2006) treat education and income inequality as subject to reverse causality and
therefore obtain instruments for these variables from a set of auxiliary regressions.  We follow the same procedure here. Amer. J. Agric. Econ. 88, 5 (2006):1304-1310, in press.                                                            Page 4
Copyright 2006 American Agricultural Economics Association
Table 1. Variables, Definitions and Descriptive Statistics
Variable Explanation Mean SD
Dependent Variables  
SKI  Social capital index, 1997 (Rupasingha et al. 2006) -4.8E-16 1.3E+00
ASSN97 Associations per 10,000 people for 1997 13.10 6.06
PVOTE00 Percent eligible voting in 2000 presidential election 53.70 10.16
NCCS  Tax-exempt non-profits per 10,000, NCCS, 1997 5.92 4.70
CENSUS00 Response rate to 2000 Census of Population 62.46 8.80
ADH2000
Per capita church adherence (Glenmary Res. 2000) 53.20 18.28
Independent Variables  
PREDUC90 Percent population 12+ yrs educ. 1990 (predicted) 69.55 9.33
ETHNIC90 Ethnic fractionalization index 1990 0.18 0.17
PRINEQ89 Mean income/median income 1989 (predicted) 1.46 0.13
FEMLAB90 Female labor force participation rate 1990 0.93 0.03
URBAN  Urban counties (0,1) 1993 0.26 0.44
RURAL  Rural counties (0,1) 1993 0.42 0.49
OWNHOU90 Percent owner-occupied houses 1990 72.78 7.49
MEDAGE90 Median age 1990 34.42 3.59
FAMHH90 Percent family households 1990 76.07 18.52
STAY90 Percent same county as in 1985 0.75 0.07
BLACK90 Percent African-Americans 1990 8.50 14.29
MEDINC89 Median income 1989 28243 6919
FAMCHI90 Percent family households with children 1990 38.75 4.98
MANEMP90 Percent manufacturing employment 1990 18.54 10.54
AGR90 Pct. agriculture, forestry, & fishing employmt. 1990 10.56 9.60
PROFEM90 Percent professional employment 1990 21.39 4.99
PCWAL87 Number of Wal-Mart™ stores per 10,000, 1987 0.10 0.21
PRDWAL98 Change in Wal-Mart™ stores, 1987-98 (predicted) 0.58 0.81
   Into this model we introduce the number of Wal-Mart stores in 1987 (the beginning of
the decade) and the predicted change in the number of stores during the 1990s decade (up
to 1998), as dictated by our data availability.  We use the predicted value from the WalMart location equation described in Goetz and Swaminathan (2006) as an instrument.  The
instrumented values correct for endogeneity bias in that Wal-Mart avoids counties where
social capital -- and resistance to the retailer -- are high.  Our null hypothesis is that the
stores have no effect, whereas the alternative is that they depress social capital stocks
through the processes described above.
Results
Our linear regression results reported in table 2 are robust to the inclusion of the Wal-Mart
treatment effect and generally consistent with the findings of Rupasingha, Goetz and
Freshwater (2006).  The first equation has the principal component measure of social capi-Amer. J. Agric. Econ. 88, 5 (2006):1304-1310, in press.                                                            Page 5
Copyright 2006 American Agricultural Economics Association
tal as the dependent variable.  Counties with more-highly educated populations, greater
ethnic homogeneity, more females in the labor force and that are rural have greater levels of
social capital stocks than communities not meeting these characteristics.  Greater shares of
non-movers (residents who lived in the same county within the last five years), AfricanAmericans and shares employed in agriculture as well as professional activities likewise
have greater stocks of social capital.  Income inequality is statistically significant at the 5 %
level but does not have the expected sign, indicating that greater income inequality was
associated with more social capital.  Median household income, the ratio of family households to total households, families with children and owner-occupied housing each have no
effects statistically in this equation.  Age exhibits an inverted-U effect, suggesting social
capital rises with age of the population to a certain point and then declines.  Social capital is
lower in counties with younger and older populations, suggesting that these age groups are
less inclined to participate in civic activities.
Table 2.  Factors Affecting Social Capital Levels in U.S. Counties: Estimation Results
Variable
Social
 Capital
Index
(see text)
Associations
per 10,000
Presidential
Voting,
2000
election
Non-profits
per 10,000
Census
Participation
Church
Adherence,
per capita
Constant
-
21.778 *** -82.20*** -59.46*** -45.67*** 18.40  -93.67***
PREDUC90 0.097 *** 0.190*** 0.790*** 0.224*** 0.005  -0.544***
ETHNIC90 -1.333 *** -0.796 -13.52*** -2.133*** -12.89 *** 32.17***
PRINEQ89 0.567 * -2.145* 3.604** 9.956*** -13.59 *** -3.057
FEMLAB90 4.355 *** 34.62*** -21.88*** 7.778 31.34 *** 115.0***
URBAN90 -0.058  -0.704*** 1.116*** -1.447*** 3.498 *** 2.910***
RURAL90 0.205 *** 0.879*** 1.122*** 0.728*** -0.807 *** 4.008***
OWNHOU90 -0.005  -0.094*** 0.421*** -0.116*** -0.243 *** -0.100*
MEDAGE90 0.228 *** 1.510*** 1.248*** 0.827*** -0.128  -4.457***
AGESQ90 -0.002 *** -0.015*** -0.012** -0.009*** -0.001  0.056***
FAMHH90 0.003  0.055*** -0.052*** -0.045*** 0.142 *** 0.471***
STAY90 6.162 *** 22.75*** 22.85*** 14.96*** 19.78 *** 95.847***
BLACK90 0.011 *** 0.038*** 0.170*** -0.012  0.027  -0.362***
MEDINC89 -1E-05  -.0001*** -.0001** 2.E-05 0.0004 *** 0.001***
FAMCHI90 0.006  0.143*** -0.061 -0.053 0.301 *** 0.986***
MANEMP90 0.005  -0.005 0.061*** -0.020 0.168 *** -0.226***
AGR90 0.010 ** -0.011 0.304*** -0.100*** 0.094 *** 0.052
PROFEM90 0.034 *** 0.114*** 0.114*** 0.064* 0.296 *** 0.059
PCWAL87 -0.130 ** 0.083 -2.313*** -1.058*** 2.046 *** 6.114***
PRDWAL98 -0.198 *** -0.875*** -0.641** -0.527*** 0.080  -3.916***
Adjusted R
2
0.61 0.41 0.56 0.39 0.50 0.48
Note: Statistical significance levels are as follows: *= ten percent, **=five percent and ***=one percent or lower.  The sample size is n = 2,978 counties. Amer. J. Agric. Econ. 88, 5 (2006):1304-1310, in press.                                                            Page 6
Copyright 2006 American Agricultural Economics Association
 As for the Wal-Mart effect, both the initial number of stores and each store added per
10,000 persons during the decade reduced the overall social capital measure.  The coefficient estimates are −0.130 and −0.198, respectively, and both are statistically different from
zero at the 5 % level.  The relative magnitudes of these variables compare with a mean of
0.0 for the dependent variable and a standard deviation of 1.3.  Thus, the effect is not large,
but it is statistically significant nevertheless.
 The second equation in table 2 contains the number of social capital-generating associations per 10,000 residents.  Here only the addition of Wal-Marts during the 1990s exerts
a statistically significant effect, not the initial number of stores in 1987.  Other regressors
also either change signs or become statistically indistinguishable from zero.  For example,
homeownership and greater median household incomes have negative effects, suggesting
substitution of private for public participation in social capital-generating activities.  Families with children and family household shares each have a positive effect on the dependent
variable.  As hypothesized, greater income inequality reduces the density of these associations significantly.
 Voter turnout, column three in table 2, likewise follows an inverted-U-shaped age
structure of the county’s population.  As was true of the two previous measures of social
capital, educational attainment exerts a statistically significant effect on this form of social
capital.  Higher income depresses voter turnout, reflecting higher opportunity costs of time,
while owner-occupied housing shares have the opposite effect.  Homeowners go to the
polls to protect their property values.  Again Wal-Mart has the predicted effect, with both
variables statistically significant at below the 5 % level, and negative.  In other words, WalMart’s presence depresses voter turnout on election day, signifying a reduction in local social capital and civic capacity (or, in this case, activity).
 In the case of tax-exempt non-profit organizations per 10,000 we again have the expected sign and statistical significance for both Wal-Mart variables at below the 1 % level.
We also obtain the inverted-U familiar from the previous three equations for age.  Female
labor force participation has no effect here statistically.  Urban areas have less of the social
capital embodied in this establishment type, as do counties with proportionately more family households.
 Another key social capital indicator is participation in the decennial Census.  While
most variables in this equation were statistically significant and had expected signs, this
was not the case for urban and rural indicator variables and home ownership.  Participation
in the Census does not vary with age structure of county population.  This equation, unexpectedly, reveals that the presence of Wal-Mart stores at the beginning of the decade increased participation rates in the 2000 census in a statistically significant manner, whereas
the arrival of new stores had no effect.   The last column in table 2 presents results for
church adherence.  Several variables have unexpected, statistically significant effects.  Contrary to our hypotheses, higher adherence levels were associated with lower educational
levels and higher ethnic diversity.   While the effect of age in most of other social capital
indicators followed an inverted-U, the opposite is observed here: church adherence is more
pronounced among younger and older populations, perhaps because these age groups have
more spare time to attend church regularly.  The results with respect to Wal-Mart are
mixed.  The presence of Wal-Mart stores at the beginning of the decade increased church
adherence, whereas growth in the number of stores (or new locations) decreased church
adherence in a statistically significant manner.   Amer. J. Agric. Econ. 88, 5 (2006):1304-1310, in press.                                                            Page 7
Copyright 2006 American Agricultural Economics Association
Conclusion
Wal-Mart responds to market opportunities and by definition ignores the local externalities
it creates within communities.  Our results indicate that the presence of Wal-Mart depresses
social capital stocks in local communities, measured here at the county-level.  Based on our
earlier work, these externalities represent real costs for communities in the form of reduced
economic growth.  Our results also indicate that community leaders should think carefully
about providing infrastructure development subsidies to the chain.  Given the measurable
impact that social capital has on economic well-being, our findings are important.  Less
clear is what should or could be done about this.  One policy response is to force the chain
to internalize these effects in its decision-making.
 Local county leaders should be made aware of the likely adverse effects of the chain on
local civic capacity and social capital, and consider implementing policies and programs to
help mitigate these effects.  Space limitations prevent us from elaborating further, but one
example is promoting local entrepreneurship through organized networks.  Another is fostering regional cooperation among local firms in related industries, and the strategic development of local clusters through partnerships with universities and local community colleges.
References
Barrett, C.B. ed. 2005. The Social Economics of Poverty. London and New York, NY: Routledge.
Durlauf, S.N., and H.P. Young. 2001. Social Dynamics. Washington, DC and Boston, MA: Brookings Institution and MIT Press.
Fishman, C. 2006. The Wal-Mart Effect: How the World’s Most Powerful Company Really Works –
and How It’s Transforming the American Economy. New York, NY: Penguin Press.
Glaeser, E.L., D. Laibson, and B. Sacerdote. 2002.  “The Economic Approach to Social Capital.”
Economic Journal 112:F437-F458.  
Goetz, S.J., and H. Swaminathan. 2006. “Wal-Mart and Family Poverty in US Counties.” Social
Sciences Quarterly 87:211-226.
Griliches, Z. 1957. “Hybrid Corn: An Exploration in the Economics of Technological Change,”
Econometrica 25:501-522.
Irwin, E.G., and J. Clark. 2006. “Wall Street vs. Main Street: What are the Benefits and Costs of
Wal-Mart to Local Communities?” Choices 21(2).  Available on-line:
http://www.choicesmagazine.org/2006-2/grabbag/2006-2-14.htm (accessed August 12, 2006).
Kahneman, D., and A.B. Krueger. 2006. “Developments in the Measurement of Subjective WellBeing.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(1):3-24.
Knack, S., and P. Keefer. 1997. “Does Social Capital Have an Economic Pay-Off?  A Cross-Country
Investigation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107:1252-88.
Layard, P.R.G. 2005. Happiness: Lessons from a New Science. New York, NY: Penguin Press.
Narayan, D., and L. Pritchett. 1999. “Cents and Sociability: Household Income and Social Capital in
Rural Tanzania.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 47:871-897.
Putnam, R. 2000.  Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. New York,
NY: Simon and Schuster. Amer. J. Agric. Econ. 88, 5 (2006):1304-1310, in press.                                                            Page 8
Copyright 2006 American Agricultural Economics Association
Rupasingha, A., S.J. Goetz, and D. Freshwater. 2002. “Social and Institutional Factors as Determinants of Economic Growth: Evidence from the United States Counties.” Papers in Regional
Science 81:139-155.
——. 2006. “The Production of Social Capital in US Counties.” Journal of Socio-Economics 35:83-
101.
Rupasingha, A., and S.J. Goetz. 2003. “The Causes of Enduring Poverty: An Expanded Spatial
Analysis of the Structural Determinants of Poverty in the US.” Rural Development Paper No.
22. The Northeast Regional Center for Rural Development, The Pennsylvania State University.
Schmid, A.A. 2003. “Discussion: Social Capital as an Important Lever in Economic Development
Policy and Private Strategy.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 85:716-719.
Skinner, J., and D. Staiger. 2005. “Technology Adoption from Hybrid Corn to Beta Blockers.”
NBER Working Paper No. 11251, Cambridge, MA.
Stone, K. 1997. “Impact of the Wal-Mart Phenomenon on Rural Communities.” in Increasing Public
Understanding of Public Problems and Policies, Farm Foundation, Oak Brook, Illinois, pp. 189-
200.
Tolbert, C.M., T.A. Lyson, and M.D. Irwin. 1998. “Local Capitalism, Civic Engagement, and Socioeconomic Well-Being.”  Social Forces 77:401-427.

No comments:

Post a Comment

Join this site to get the latest updates & insight. Make friends and more...

HeyoCritiq, who....

Well, I am basically a critic..neither a supporter nor a sympathizer of any political party.....or the high and the mighty. A former freelance journalist and (amateur) photographer who once made a living thus! A cheerful and jolly guy, completely self made, moderately educated, well read and travelled, gathering great experiences; learning from the thick and thin and deriving the wisdom of life. One who learns from everyone and firmly believes its a continuous process. Fairly honest who takes pride in calling a spade a spade and has a direct approach. Gets inspired by the honoured and the humble. Unsparing. A critic. Does not hesitate to self criticize; in fact, welcomes criticism and laughs over it / corrects if & when possible. An ardent believer and lover of God;strongly believe in Him as the Creator and the Destroyer.A devout man.........believes that God is the Ultimate & the Almighty. Nothing happens without him. A lot more.......

Disclaimer


Views expressed here are solely that of the writers.
Best efforts have been taken to ensure there is no infringement of any copyright or any other infringement related to IPR or any other rights or properties whatsoever. Should there be any, please bring it to our attention enabling removal / rectification asap and acknowledgement of the same if possible.

There is no intention whatsoever to hurt anyone's feeling in any way. Readers are free to comment / air their views and feelings. Efforts shall be taken to correct / amend if required and if possible.

Advertisements are NOT selected or decided by me. Products or services advertised here are NOT vouched or endorsed by Heyo Critiq.

IF HAPPY TELL OTHERS. IF NOT, TELL ME. HeyoCritiq